There are strong institutional reasons for the lagging performance against its regional neighbors
In the 70 years since World War II ended, East Asian economies,
including Malaysia, appear to have largely got performance right.
Malaysia was also one of 13 countries identified by the Commission on
Growth and Development in its 2008
Growth Report
to have recorded average growth of more than 7 percent per year for 25
years or more. Malaysia achieved this spectacular performance from 1967
to 1997.
However, since the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997 and1998, Malaysia’s
economic performance when compared to previous decades has been
lackluster and most macroeconomic indicators are trending downwards.
This was confirmed by Prime Minister Najib Tun Razak himself in the
publication on March 30, 2010 of the
New Economic Model – Part 1.
This was a very brave move but a necessary one by the premier as he
acknowledged publicly the failures of Malaysia’s current economic model
in order to demonstrate urgency for reforms.
The New Economic Model identifies domestic factors such as weak investor
confidence, capability constraints (weak human capital, entrepreneurial
base and innovative capacity) , productivity ceilings and institutional
degradation and external factors such as a sluggish global economy
caused by the global financial crisis of 2008-2009 and the rise of
neighbors in the region in contributing to the declining growth
trajectory.
If we were to revisit the determinants of growth and agree that proper
institutions form the overall structure that determines long-term
sustainable growth, then the logical response is to reform Malaysia’s
institutional set-up, as it must be the deepest determinant of what is
hindering economic growth.
This view is further strengthened as Malaysia’s other deep determinants,
geography and trade, are favorable. The country has abundant natural
resources, is shielded from natural hazards and is well-located
strategically both geopolitically and economically. Malaysia has also
benefitted tremendously from being an open economy, especially in the
merchandise sector.
The New Economic Model also reports that regional challenges from China,
India and Vietnam, etc. are a cause for Malaysia’s declining economic
performance. What has changed about these countries? They have all
undertaken institutional reforms: China since 1978, India since 1992 and
Vietnam since 1986. They are reaping the benefits while Malaysia has
stalled in its institutional reforms since the 1990s, regressed in some
ways and is suffering from the consequences.
The above points stress the importance of institutional reforms in
Malaysia, something that Najib has ironically neglected in his
signature policies –
1Malaysia,
Government Transformation Programme and
Economic Transformation Programme.
According to the Growth Commission report, “…fast sustained growth is
not a miracle; it is attainable for developing countries with the ‘right
mix of ingredients.’ Countries need leaders who are committed to
achieving growth and who can take advantage of opportunities from the
global economy. They also need to know about the levels of incentives
and public investments that are necessary for private investment to take
off and ensure the long-term diversification of the economy and its
integration in the global economy…”
Michael Spence, the Chairman of the Growth Commission, elaborated on his
extensive experience working with developing countries on growth issues
in his latest
book
by emphasizing two important characteristics for developing countries
to ensure long term sustainable growth – the role of political
leadership and democratic norms. He suggests four characteristics for
governments that are necessary requirements to underpin long term
growth:
- The government takes economic performance and growth seriously.
- The governing group has values that cause it to try to act in
the interest of the vast majority of the people (as opposed to
themselves or some subgroup, however defined)
- The government is competent and effective and selects a viable
sustained-growth strategy that includes openness to the global economy,
high levels of investment, and a strong future orientation.
- Economic freedom is present and is supported by the legal system and regulatory policy
Manifestations of Malay/Muslim Supremacy
Malaysia is classified as a non-democratic state by all international
indexes measuring quality of democracy. This is also affirmed in
academic circles. During the boom years, Malaysians accepted this
tradeoff – restricted freedom for economic growth. Since 1997/98, this
has changed as expected. The government has not delivered on growth,
therefore the natural demand for reforms and by extension freedom.
There is consensus that Malaysia needs extensive economic, political and
social reforms. This is all the more evident IF we agree that
institutions are key to long term growth. Also, IF we agree with Spence,
these reforms must come from a government with the four characteristics
identified above.
Astute observers of Malaysia know the reasons why the present
administration and the ones before were unable to make fundamental
reforms. This has much to do with the ideology of Malay/Muslim Supremacy
as defined by the United Malays National Organization (UMNO) and
accepted by large swaths of Malaysians, Muslims and non-Muslims alike.
From the literature we can infer that the ideology of Malay/Muslim
supremacy has provided the perverse incentives that have manifested
themselves in many ways. The more critical ones are:
- Institutional degradation: The deterioration in the quality of
Malaysia’s institutions, particularly during former Prime Minister
Mahathir Mohamad’s years, such as the lack of independence between the
branches of government; the politicization of the civil service,
producing a culture of risk aversion and a lack of creativity; and the
expansion of the non-transparent Government Linked Corporations (GLCs):
- Crony capitalism: Affirmative action in the name of Malays has
become a smokescreen for crony capitalism. Affirmative action is the
instrument for rampant elite-based (from all races, not only Malays)
corruption. High levels of income inequality in Malaysia in general but
more so within the Malay community prove this.
- Race based affirmative action: Race-based affirmative action in
itself is recognized as one of the important reasons for Malaysia’s
declining economic performance. Malaysia’s focus on the ex-post
equalization of outcomes across ethnicities rather than ensuring
effective ex-ante equalization of access to opportunities has had
important direct efficiency implications, affecting growth by distorting
incentives and thereby the competitive process.
- Excessive centralization: An interesting institutional feature
is the lack of decentralization in the country, which is nominally a
Federation and the top-down approach in public policymaking. This is a
key disconnect in the reform rhetoric in the ETP and GTP. To strengthen
public service delivery, local communities need to be empowered. Fiscal
relationships between federal-state-local also demonstrates
institutional failure.
- Feedback mechanisms: Related to Malaysia’s top-down approaches
is an almost complete disregard for monitoring and evaluation. As a
result there is little feedback from outcomes into policy design. The
obsession with centralizing policy-making is also evident in lack of
information sharing both within government and with the public.
The need to remove UMNO to create a new “people based ideology”
In relation to competency, the quality of the human capital base in
Malaysia is suspect. This is due to the quality of education from
preschool through tertiary and on-the-job training. It is linked with
ethnicity issues and is exacerbated by the outflow of high-skill
individuals and affected by the inflow of low-skill labor.
There are not only problems on the supply side of the market for skills,
but also on the demand side, where firms may not be competitive enough
to offer higher wages. The market for skills itself is also problematic
in that the price mechanism does not work adequately and this is where
wage-setting issues play a role.
A bigger and more important challenge than competency is the question of
internal competition. This is quite distinct from external
competitiveness, on which front Malaysia has scored relatively well in
the merchandise sector given its stage of development and the nature of
its manufacturing processes which are still dominated by competitiveness
identified by low cost rather than high value.
Internal competition refers to the allocation of certain factors
including labor, capital, land and product markets. Internal competition
works well when there is good governance, openness and transparency. It
relates to the need for deregulation, liberalization and competition
policies especially in key areas such as government procurement and the
activities of GLCs in the domestic economy.
All of these are also needed to produce effective competition for good
ideas and good policies as well as competition in the political arena.
This of course challenges the basic idea of meritocracy and affirmative
action in Malaysia.
To reform these will ostensibly mean changing Malaysia’s embedded
incentives and institutions. This definitely means undoing the
manifestations of Malay/Muslim supremacy.
Can UMNO implement these reforms?
My hypothesis is that the present leadership in Malaysia within the
Barisan Nasional framework is incapable of institutionalizing reforms as
the present leadership does not meet the criteria set out by Spence for
a simple reason – its ideology. This ideology that overrides and at the
same time influences all other norms, rules, conventions, habits and
values is the ideology of Malay/Muslim Supremacy.
As the Prime Minister of Malaysia always comes from UMNO it will be
impossible for him or her to undo the cornerstone ideology of his/her
political party and its adherents in the Barisan Nasional, which
includes Malays and non-Malays.
The logic above is discussed extensively in the political science
literature. To summarize, the Malay/Muslim ideology provides
psychological and material benefits to its adherents. This makes it a
potent force for groups that rely on this ideology. However, since it is
deeply embedded, it is also extremely difficult to counter when needed.
Malaysia’s present institutional equilibrium is a reflection of the
strength of the adherents of Malay/Muslim supremacy, known by its
Malay-language slogan Ketuanan Melayu.
There are many examples to illustrate Malay/Muslim supremacy but the one
that is cited most often as holding back Malaysia’s economic reforms is
affirmative action, the most comprehensive in the world. It has by
inference been touted as the one of the key reasons for Malaysia’s
declining economic performance although causality has not been
explicitly demonstrated.
Supporters of affirmative action argue that Article 153 of the Federal
Constitution provides the Bumiputeras the right to this extensive
affirmative action. However this is factually incorrect.
Article 153 of the
Malaysian Federal Constitution states that:
153. (1) It shall be the responsibility of the Yang di-Pertuan Agong to
safeguard the special position of the Malays and natives of any of the
States of Sabah and Sarawak and the legitimate interests of other
communities in accordance with the provisions of this Article.
(2) Notwithstanding anything in this Constitution, but subject to the
provisions of Article 40 and of this Article, the Yang di-Pertuan Agong
shall exercise his functions under this Constitutions and federal law in
such manner as may be necessary to safeguard the special position of
the Malays and natives of any of the States of Sabah and Sarawak and to
ensure the reservation for Malays and natives of any of the States of
Sabah and Sarawak of such proportion as he may deem reasonable of
positions in the public service (other than the public service of a
State) and of scholarships, exhibitions and other similar educational or
training privileges or special facilities given or accorded by the
Federal Government and, when any permit or license for the operation of
any trade or business is required by federal law, then, subject to the
provisions of that law and this Article, of such permits and licenses.
In more simple words, the Federal Constitution limits affirmative action
to placement in the civil service at the Federal level, scholarships
and permits and licences for Bumiputras and only if necessary and in a
reasonable manner by the Prime Minister who advises the Yang diPertuan
Agung.
Does the Prime Minister have the power to revoke or reform affirmative action policies?
Yes, he does. Malaysia is a constitutional monarchy
where the monarch reigns but do not rule. Article 153 is subject to
Article 40 and Article 40 states that the Yang diPertuan Agung must act
on the advice of the Cabinet.
40. (1) In the exercise of his functions under this Constitution or
federal law the Yang di-Pertuan Agong shall act in accordance with the
advice of the Cabinet or of a Minister acting under the general
authority of the Cabinet, except as otherwise provided by this
Constitution; but shall be entitled, at his request, to any information
concerning the government of the Federation which is available to the
Cabinet.
The decision to continue or reform affirmative action policies
and the attendant institutions in Malaysia lies solely at the
prerogative of the Prime Minister along with his colleagues in Cabinet
as stated in Article 40.
With power centralized in the Executive (Cabinet), and with the Prime
Minister already having six Ministers of 31 from the Prime Minister’s
Department in the Cabinet, and with the Prime Minister himself holding
two portfolios (Prime Minister and Finance Minister I), and legitimised
by the Constitution (Article 40), the Prime Minister should on all
counts, be able to implement these reforms without much difficulty.
Yet he has been unable to do so for the simple reason that the Federal
Constitution may be the law of the land but it is clearly not the
supreme power/ideology in Malaysia. The supreme power/ideology is the
primacy of Malays/Muslims as defined by UMNO. Hence the Prime Minister
may have de jure power to reform, but he does not have de facto power.
This power resides among the Malays and non-Malays who support
Malay/Muslim supremacy and the current institutional set-up.
Until and unless this supreme ideology of Malay/Muslim supremacy is
removed, Malaysian politicians will be constrained in making the
necessary institutional reforms to move Malaysia towards long term
sustainable growth.
(Greg Lopez is a PhD candidate at the Crawford School of Economics and Government, Australian National University. A longer scholarly version of this appeared on The New Mandala.)